Banking in ancient Rome

Last updated

In ancient Rome there were a variety of officials tasked with banking. These were the argentarii, mensarii, coactores, and nummulari. The argentarii were money changers. The role of the mensarii was to help people through economic hardships, the coactores were hired to collect money and give it to their employer, and the nummulari minted and tested currency. They offered credit systems and loans. Between 260 and the fourth century CE Roman bankers disappear from the historical record, likely because of economic difficulties caused by the debasement of the currency.

Contents

History

The earliest banks in ancient Rome were located in temples. [1] [2] [3] They would charge interest on loans, exchange money, and track their finances through written records. Due to the piety of the officials and employees of these temples, the upper class of ancient Rome trusted these places to protect and hold their wealth. Typically, their money was stored in multiple temples. This practice was designed to protect their wealth in case an individual temple was destroyed or attacked in some way.

Another banking group in ancient Rome were the trapezites. [4] They were predecessors of the argentarii, [5] and they provided banking services in counting houses near the Forum. Roman bankers disappear from the historical record between 260 CE and the fourth century; [6] likely because the continued debasement of the currency hurt the economy, creating difficulties for the banking profession. [1] [2] By the mid-fourth century CE the argentarii and numularii are mentioned again in ancient sources; however they acquired different roles. [3]

Types

Argentarii

Arch of the Argentarii in Rome Arco degli Argentarii - lato esterno - Panairjdde.jpeg
Arch of the Argentarii in Rome

The argentarii, also known as argenteae mensae exercitores, negotiatores stipis argentariae, [10] [11] and argenti distractores, were private money changers in ancient Rome supervised by the government. [12] [13] [14] This group was organized into a guild with a limited number of members. They were commonly located at stalls, shops, tabernae, and in the forum. [15] These locations were built by the censors and owned by the state. [16] [17]

The argentarii provided numerous services, such as providing loans, [18] holding money, circulating money, exchanging currency, [19] providing credit at auctions, and determining the quality and material of currency. They were also entrusted with paying off debts. [20] Their powers would expand to include almost all forms of financial transactions. Despite this, their primary goal was to exchange foreign currency for Roman currency. [17] Typically the clients of this group were not wealthy, as the upper class of ancient Rome had more secure methods of storing wealth. [21]

Another group known as the expectores were tasked with keeping financial records, including those of the argentarii. [22] The argentarii were likely founded around the 4th century BCE. When they were established, they likely only functioned as a replacement for the previous Greek trapezitai and their abilities were likely limited to money-handling. [23] By the 1st century BCE they were capable of providing credit. [24] They disappeared from the historical record for around 70 to 80 years after 250 CE for unknown reasons. [25]

Mensarii

The mensarii were state-appointed public bankers. [26] [27] [28] Usually they were appointed during periods of poverty or war. Their goal was to prevent social unrest and help the plebeians overcome debt and economic hardships. [29] [30] [31] This organization was established in 352 BCE to combat high levels of debt as a five-man commission known as the quinqueviri mensarii. [32] [33] They accomplished this by providing the population access to public services and loans as well as managing the circulation of currency. [34] [35] [36]

This group would evolve into the triumviri mensarii in 216 BCE. [37] [38] [39] This was a commission of only three people, but performed the same duties as the previous organization. [40] [41] These two groups could perform similar functions to the argentarii, such as money holding and assaying currency. [17] [42] [15]

Coactores

An ancient Roman coin produced by the Imperial mint CarinusAureus.jpg
An ancient Roman coin produced by the Imperial mint

The coactores collected and gave money to their employers. [43] [44] [45] They were used by the argentarii for this function since the 1st century BCE, and they disappeared from the historical record after the 2nd century CE. This organization was distinct from the argentarii. [46]

There was another group in ancient Rome known as the coactores argentarii, who were responsible for depositing money and collecting debts at auctions. [47] [48] Neither of these groups provided credit to companies,[ clarification needed ] nor did they grant loans to finance consumption; although they granted short-term commercial loans. [49]

Nummularii

The nummularii were a group designed to mint and test new currency. To do this they examined the metal which was used to make the coins using their senses and the patterns of the coins. [27] They first appeared in the historical record in the 2nd century BCE as money-changers. By the 2nd century CE they began to provide loans, deposit currency, and operate bank accounts.

They ran a bank and put new currency into circulation and they removed foreign or old coins from circulation. [50] Alongside this they could hold money, sell goods, work at auctions, maintain records, exchange currency, and make payments on behalf of their clients. [17] [38] By the 3rd century, they were the last banking profession in ancient Rome, and they handled all banking affairs. [46] [51]

Privileges and organization

Ancient Roman denarius Q. Pompeius Rufus, denarius, 54 BC, RRC 434-2.jpg
Ancient Roman denarius

Roman bankers provided a wide variety of services. They would serve as cashiers and money changers, they could sell goods at auctions, and they could determine the material and quality of currency or open money bases. If this base was irregular or open then the banker was permitted to reinvest or reuse the client's money. Their activities were concluded and recorded with written agreements. [52] In early Roman history most contracts were conducted orally, with witnesses used to confirm the legitimacy of the agreement. Later notaries were used to keep public written records of contracts. [47] [53] Roman bankers belonged to the plebeian or freedmen classes rather than the aristocracy. [54] [55] [56] However they sometimes became very wealthy. Typically they organized themselves into groups of two or three members. Many children of these bankers achieved equestrian rank. [25]

Roman bankers were allowed to open bank accounts. [57] These accounts were entered in a register. If a Roman was involved in a lawsuit, they were required to create these accounts. This was because these accounts were considered reliable proof in lawsuit cases. Bankers participated in the receptum argentarii, [58] an agreement that involved three people: the banker, the client, and the third party. The banker would pay the money the client owned to the third party.[ clarification needed ] [59] Stipulation was common in ancient Rome: the debtor was questioned by the creditor in the presence of witnesses, about their willingness to pay back the debt. Written contracts were used to document the transfer of the creditor's loan to the debtor. These contracts were usually simple due to the illiteracy of the Roman population. [60] Since Roman banks lacked any incentive to ensure that their client's deposits would remain safe during a bank run, they usually kept less in reserves than the full amount of their clients deposits; they were not required to insure their customers' deposits. [48] [61] There was very little regulation of Roman bankers, with most banks and bankers relying on trust. This meant that the clients lacked any protection or safety net in the event of a bank run or a financial crisis.

Credit

The nummularii offered a rudimentary credit system and they provided moneylending services. [62] The coactores and the argentarii also gave credit to buyers at auctions. [21] [25] [24] Credit services may also have been provided by entrepreneurs known as the faeneratores. [63] [44] Aristocratic financers were another source of credit. They used their own wealth to fund their loans to other members of the upper class or to foreign cities and nobles. Following auctions the coactores and the argentarii would impose on the buyers a time-limit for their payment, and they would pay the vendors the money which was owed to them. [46] [64] Although these financial services were necessary for starting a business, almost all Romans would have engaged in credit. [65] Most credit arrangements lasted a month, with an interest rate of 1% (per month). [60] The Romans believed that anyone involved in trade should use credit. [61] People who provided credit might also have sold their right to collect the debt to another party. In ancient Rome credit transactions relied on trust. It was common for people to lose trust in their creditors, often resulting in a significant negative impact on the economy and the credit industry. [66] [67]

Loans

Loan defaults carried severe penalties, as their borrowers could be enslaved, mutilated, or sued. [68] Most ancient Roman loans were linked to consumption, which is the use of resources to satisfy wants or needs. [69] These loans allowed merchants to restock their goods more quickly and it allowed them to purchase more goods. [25] They were often essential, as it was almost impossible for many people to live in ancient Rome without debt. [70] Usually Roman loans were given to young nobles and they generally had high interest rates. [71] [72] [73] Another common option was to give loans to close family or friends as a method of averting risk. [74] It is possible that ancient Roman loans lacked a security deposit. [75] [76] However, ancient loans did require some form of security. [77] Usually, loans were made and credits were extended on risky terms because the available capital typically exceeded the amount needed by borrowers. [78] The senatorial elite were involved heavily in private lending, as both creditors and borrowers, and made loans from their personal fortunes on the basis of social connections. [48] [61]

There were a variety of types of ancient Roman loans. One kind, known as a mutuum, was made without interest. Under this kind of loan the property rights passed to the banker. They were returned when the debt was paid off. Loans with interest were known as fenus or usura. Another kind of loan was the fenus nauticum or pecunia traiecticia. It was contracted between two individuals with the aid of an intermediary. It was common for the banks to play the role of the intermediary. [79] [80]

See also

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Central bank</span> Government body that manages currency and monetary policy

A central bank, reserve bank, or monetary authority is an institution that manages the currency and monetary policy of a country or monetary union. In contrast to a commercial bank, a central bank possesses a monopoly on increasing the monetary base. Many central banks also have supervisory or regulatory powers to ensure the stability of commercial banks in their jurisdiction, to prevent bank runs, and in some cases also to enforce policies on financial consumer protection and against bank fraud, money laundering, or terrorism financing.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Basilica</span> Type of building in classical and church architecture

In Ancient Roman architecture, a basilica was a large public building with multiple functions that was typically built alongside the town's forum. The basilica was in the Latin West equivalent to a stoa in the Greek East. The building gave its name to the architectural form of the basilica.

A saeculum is a length of time roughly equal to the potential lifetime of a person or, equivalently, the complete renewal of a human population.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Monetary reform</span> Movements to amend the financial systeem

Monetary reform is any movement or theory that proposes a system of supplying money and financing the economy that is different from the current system.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">William Ormsby-Gore, 4th Baron Harlech</span> British peer, politician and honorary military colonel

William George Arthur Ormsby-Gore, 4th Baron Harlech,, was a British Conservative politician and banker.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Roman commerce</span> Major sector of the Roman economy

Roman commerce was a major sector of the Roman economy during the later generations of the Republic and throughout most of the imperial period. Fashions and trends in historiography and in popular culture have tended to neglect the economic basis of the empire in favor of the lingua franca of Latin and the exploits of the Roman legions. The language and the legions were supported by trade and were part of its backbone. The Romans were businessmen, and the longevity of their empire was caused by their commercial trade.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Lucius Caecilius Iucundus</span> 1st century CE Roman banker

Lucius Caecilius Iucundus was a banker who lived in the Roman town of Pompeii around AD 14–62. His house still stands and can be seen in the ruins of the city of Pompeii which remain after being partially destroyed by the eruption of Vesuvius in AD 79. The house is known both for its frescoes and for the trove of wax tablets discovered there in 1875, which gave scholars access to the records of Iucundus' banking operations.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Cirta</span> Ancient Berber and Roman settlement

Cirta, also known by various other names in antiquity, was the ancient Berber and Roman settlement which later became Constantine, Algeria.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Frumentarii</span> Ancient Roman intelligence agency

The frumentarii were an ancient Roman military and secret police organization used as an intelligence agency. They began their history as a courier service and developed into an imperial spying agency. Their organization would also carry out assassinations. The frumentarii were headquartered in the Castra Peregrina and were run by the princeps peregrinorum. They were disbanded under the reign of Diocletian due to their poor reputation amongst the populace.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Roman economy</span> Economy of ancient Rome

The study of the economies of the ancient city-state of Rome and its empire during the Republican and Imperial periods remains highly speculative. There are no surviving records of business and government accounts, such as detailed reports of tax revenues, and few literary sources regarding economic activity. Instead, the study of this ancient economy is today mainly based on the surviving archeological and literary evidence that allow researchers to form conjectures based on comparisons with other more recent pre-industrial economies.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">History of banking</span> Aspect of History

The history of banking began with the first prototype banks, that is, the merchants of the world, who gave grain loans to farmers and traders who carried goods between cities. This was around 2000 BC in Assyria, India and Sumer. Later, in ancient Greece and during the Roman Empire, lenders based in temples gave loans, while accepting deposits and performing the change of money. Archaeology from this period in ancient China and India also shows evidence of money lending.

The history of money is the development over time of systems for the exchange, storage, and measurement of wealth. Money is a means of fulfilling these functions indirectly and in general rather than directly, as with barter.

A financial crisis is any of a broad variety of situations in which some financial assets suddenly lose a large part of their nominal value. In the 19th and early 20th centuries, many financial crises were associated with banking panics, and many recessions coincided with these panics. Other situations that are often called financial crises include stock market crashes and the bursting of other financial bubbles, currency crises, and sovereign defaults. Financial crises directly result in a loss of paper wealth but do not necessarily result in significant changes in the real economy.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Ancile</span>

In ancient Rome, the ancilia were twelve sacred shields kept in the Temple of Mars. According to legend, one divine shield fell from heaven during the reign of Numa Pompilius, the second king of Rome. He ordered eleven copies made to confuse would-be thieves, since the original shield was regarded as one of the pignora imperii , sacred guarantors that perpetuated Rome as a sovereign entity.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Money</span> Object or record accepted as payment

Money is any item or verifiable record that is generally accepted as payment for goods and services and repayment of debts, such as taxes, in a particular country or socio-economic context. The primary functions which distinguish money are: medium of exchange, a unit of account, a store of value and sometimes, a standard of deferred payment.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Licinius II</span> Roman caesar from 317 to 324

Licinius II, also called Licinius Junior or Licinius Caesar, was the son of the Roman emperor Licinius I. He held the imperial rank of caesar between March 317 and September 324, while his father was augustus, and he was twice Roman consul. After losing a civil war, his father lost power and both he and Licinius the Younger were eventually put to death.

The first plague pandemic was the first historically recorded Old World pandemic of plague, the contagious disease caused by the bacterium Yersinia pestis. Also called the early medieval pandemic, it began with the Plague of Justinian in 541 and continued until 750 or 767; at least fifteen or eighteen major waves of plague following the Justinianic plague have been identified from historical records. The pandemic affected the Mediterranean Basin most severely and most frequently, but also infected the Near East and Northern Europe, and potentially East Asia as well. The Roman emperor Justinian I's name is sometimes applied to the whole series of plague epidemics in late Antiquity.

The banker of ancient times was employed within financial activities, during the ancient Mesopotamian, ancient Greek and ancient Roman periods.

Kristina Milnor is Professor of Classics in the Department of Classics and Ancient Studies at Barnard College, Columbia University. She specialises in Latin literature, Roman history, feminist theory and gender studies.

There were four primary kinds of taxation in ancient Rome: a cattle tax, a land tax, customs, and a tax on the profits of any profession. These taxes were typically collected by local aristocrats. The Roman state would set a fixed amount of money each region needed to provide in taxes, and the local officials would decide who paid the taxes and how much they paid. Once collected the taxes would be used to fund the military, create public works, establish trade networks, stimulate the economy, and to fund the cursus publicum.

References

  1. 1 2 Depeyrot, Georges; Porter, Catherine; Stahl, Alan M. StahlAlan M. (1 January 2005), "Money-changing", The Oxford Encyclopedia of Economic History, Oxford University Press, doi:10.1093/acref/9780195105070.001.0001, ISBN   978-0-19-510507-0, archived from the original on 3 August 2022, retrieved 3 August 2022
  2. 1 2 Kay, Philip (2014). "After the Credit Crunch". Rome's Economic Revolution. Oxford University Press. pp. 235–265. doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199681549.003.0011. ISBN   978-0-19-968154-9.
  3. 1 2 Elliott, Colin P. (2014). "The Acceptance and Value of Roman Silver Coinage in the Second and Third Centuries AD". The Numismatic Chronicle. 174: 129–152. JSTOR   44710189.
  4. Temin, Peter (September 2004). "Financial Intermediation in the Early Roman Empire". The Journal of Economic History. Cambridge University Press. 64 (3): 705–733. doi:10.1017/S0022050704002943. hdl: 1721.1/63609 . JSTOR   3874817. S2CID   154894486. ProQuest   216404189 via Cambridge Core.
  5. Munro, John; Thomas, W. A. (2007), "Banking and Credit", The Oxford Encyclopedia of Maritime History, Oxford University Press, doi:10.1093/acref/9780195130751.001.0001, ISBN   978-0-19-513075-1, archived from the original on 3 August 2022, retrieved 3 August 2022
  6. Silver, Morris (2011). "Finding the Roman Empire's disappeared deposit bankers". Historia: Zeitschrift für Alte Geschichte. 60 (3): 301–327. JSTOR   41342853.
  7. Fischer, Julia C. (26 July 2019). Art in Rome: From Antiquity to the Present. Cambridge Scholars Publishing. pp. 98–100. ISBN   978-1-5275-3752-1. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  8. Aicher, Peter J. (2004). Rome Alive: A Source-Guide to the Ancient City Volume II (in Latin). Bolchazy-Carducci Publishers. p. 157. ISBN   978-0-86516-507-6. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  9. Elsner, Jaś (2005). "Sacrifice and narrative on the Arch of the Argentarii at Rome". Journal of Roman Archaeology. 18: 83–98. doi:10.1017/S1047759400007224. S2CID   188993120.
  10. Nauta, Lodi (2018). "Latin as a Common Language: The Coherence of Lorenzo Valla's Humanist Program". Renaissance Quarterly. 71 (1): 1–32. doi:10.1086/696885. JSTOR   26560745. S2CID   165408104. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 22 August 2022.
  11. Peneder, Michael (January 2022). "Digitization and the evolution of money as a social technology of account". Journal of Evolutionary Economics. 32 (1): 175–203. doi: 10.1007/s00191-021-00729-4 .
  12. Mayumi, Kozo Torasan (2020). "Beyond the Conventional View: Reconsidering Money, Credit and Interest". Sustainable Energy and Economics in an Aging Population. Lecture Notes in Energy. Vol. 76. Springer Science+Business Media. pp. 79–97. doi:10.1007/978-3-030-43225-6_4. ISBN   978-3-030-43224-9. S2CID   216414842.
  13. Darley, Rebecca (22 March 2018), "argentarius", The Oxford Dictionary of Late Antiquity, Oxford University Press, doi:10.1093/acref/9780198662778.001.0001, ISBN   978-0-19-866277-8, archived from the original on 3 August 2022, retrieved 1 August 2022
  14. Campbell, Gordon (2007), "Severus, (Lucius) Septimius", The Grove Encyclopedia of Classical Art and Architecture, Oxford University Press, doi:10.1093/acref/9780195300826.001.0001, ISBN   978-0-19-530082-6, archived from the original on 3 August 2022, retrieved 2 August 2022
  15. 1 2 Smith, William (24 July 2021). "Mensarii". A Smaller Dictionary of Greek and Roman Antiquities. DigiCat. pp. 254–255. Archived from the original on 5 July 2022. Retrieved 3 August 2022.
  16. Schmitz, Leonhard (1875). "Argentarii". A Dictionary of Greek and Roman Antiquities. London: John Murray. pp. 130–132. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 22 August 2022.
  17. 1 2 3 4 Labate, Victor (17 November 2016). "Banking in the Roman World". World History Encyclopedia. Archived from the original on 30 July 2022. Retrieved 30 July 2022.
  18. Rauh, Nicholas K. (1989). "Finance and Estate Sales in Republican Rome". Aevum. 63 (1): 45–76. JSTOR   20858375 via JSTOR.
  19. Lothian, James R. LothianJames R. (1 January 2005), "Exchange Rates", The Oxford Encyclopedia of Economic History, Oxford University Press, doi:10.1093/acref/9780195105070.001.0001, ISBN   978-0-19-510507-0, archived from the original on 3 August 2022, retrieved 2 August 2022
  20. Moshenskyi, Sergii (2008). History of the Weksel: Bill of Exchange and Promissory Note. New York: Xlibris. pp. 40–41. ISBN   978-1-4363-0694-2. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  21. 1 2 MacDonald, Scott B. (12 July 2017). A History of Credit and Power in the Western World. Routledge. ISBN   978-1-351-53532-8. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  22. Last, Richard (May 2021). "A Fictive Membership Rush and Curatorial Fraud in the Lex of the Collegivm of Ivory and Citrus-Wood Merchants (Cil 6.3885 = Ils 7214)". The Classical Quarterly. Cambridge University Press. 71 (1): 347–358. doi:10.1017/S0009838821000392. S2CID   235747647. ProQuest   2548800396 via Cambridge Core.
  23. Sarris, Peter (22 March 2018), "finance", The Oxford Dictionary of Late Antiquity, Oxford University Press, doi:10.1093/acref/9780198662778.001.0001, ISBN   978-0-19-866277-8, archived from the original on 3 August 2022, retrieved 1 August 2022
  24. 1 2 Lintott, Andrew (2002). "Freedmen and Slaves in the Light of Legal Documents from First-Century A.D. Campania". The Classical Quarterly. Cambridge University Press. 52 (2): 555–565. doi:10.1093/cq/52.2.555. JSTOR   3556419. INIST   14564960 ProQuest   201672538 via Cambridge Core.
  25. 1 2 3 4 Andreau, J. (2000). "Commerce and finance". The Cambridge Ancient History. Cambridge University Press. pp. 769–786. doi:10.1017/CHOL9780521263351.027. ISBN   9781139054393 via Cambridge Core.
  26. Niczyporuk, Piotr (15 March 2014). "Bankierzy w Żywotach cezarów Swetoniusza" [Bankers in The Twelve Caesars by Suetonius]. Krytyka Prawa (in Polish). 2014 (1). doi: 10.7206/kp.2080-1084.54 .
  27. 1 2 Niczyporuk, Piotr (2014). "Nummularii – государственные и частные банкиры в древнем Риме". Miscellanea Historico-Iuridica (in Russian). 12 (1): 57–74. doi: 10.15290/mhi.2013.12.03 .
  28. Abramova, Marianna G.; Vasilieva, Oxana N.; Milovanova, Marina M.; Popova, Anna V.; Yudenkov, Yuri N.; Safonov, Maxim S. (1 November 2016). "Banks: Old Actors of the New Economy". International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues. 6 (8): 84–89. ProQuest   1846293526. Archived from the original on 22 August 2022. Retrieved 22 August 2022.
  29. Bernard, Seth (16 August 2018). Building Mid-Republican Rome: Labor, Architecture, and the Urban Economy. Oxford University Press. ISBN   978-0-19-087880-1. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  30. Bringmann, Klaus (2014). "The Roman Republic and its Internal Politics between 232 and 167bc". A Companion to Livy. pp. 394–406. doi:10.1002/9781118339015.ch29. ISBN   978-1-118-33901-5.
  31. Develin, Robert (2005). "The Integration of the Plebeians into the Political Order After 366 B.C.". Social Struggles in Archaic Rome. pp. 293–311. doi:10.1002/9780470752753.ch12. ISBN   9780470752753.
  32. Bernard, Seth (November 2018). "The Social History of Early Roman Coinage". Journal of Roman Studies. 108: 1–26. doi: 10.1017/S0075435818000497 . JSTOR   26817562. S2CID   165504116. ProQuest   2193724986.
  33. Humm, Michel (2014). "From 390bcto Sentinum: Political and Ideological Aspects". A Companion to Livy. pp. 342–366. doi:10.1002/9781118339015.ch26. ISBN   978-1-118-33901-5.
  34. Vishnia, Rachel Feig (12 November 2012). State, Society and Popular Leaders in Mid-Republican Rome 241-167 B.C. Routledge. pp. 86–89. ISBN   978-1-135-09371-6. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  35. Niczyporuk, Piotr (2012). "Mensarii – как банкиры". Miscellanea Historico-Iuridica (in Russian). 11 (1): 61–76. doi: 10.15290/mhi.2012.11.03 .
  36. Potter, David S. (2010), "Magistrates and Officials, Roman", The Oxford Encyclopedia of Ancient Greece and Rome, Oxford University Press, doi:10.1093/acref/9780195170726.001.0001, ISBN   978-0-19-517072-6, archived from the original on 3 August 2022, retrieved 2 August 2022
  37. Smith, Christopher (2018). "Introduction". Omnium Annalium Monumenta: Historical Writing and Historical Evidence in Republican Rome. pp. 1–13. doi:10.1163/9789004355552_002. ISBN   978-90-04-35555-2. S2CID   239585025.
  38. 1 2 Hollander, D. B. (2007). "Financial Instruments". Money in the Late Roman Republic. pp. 31–58. doi:10.1163/ej.9789004156494.i-196.17. ISBN   978-90-474-1912-9.
  39. Ñaco Del Hoyo, Toni (2011). "Roman Economy, Finance, and Politics in the Second Punic War". A Companion to the Punic Wars. pp. 376–392. doi:10.1002/9781444393712.ch21. ISBN   978-1-4443-9371-2.
  40. "triumviri". Oxford Reference. Archived from the original on 3 August 2022. Retrieved 2 August 2022.
  41. Bernard, Seth (2016). "Debt, Land, and Labor in the Early Republican Economy". Phoenix. 70 (3/4): 317–338. doi:10.7834/phoenix.70.3-4.0317. JSTOR   10.7834/phoenix.70.3-4.0317. S2CID   164545996. Project MUSE   808005 ProQuest   1937846677.
  42. von Reden, Sitta (18 November 2010). Money in Classical Antiquity. Cambridge University Press. p. 115. ISBN   978-1-139-78863-2. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  43. Westgate, Ruth (November 2001). "K. M. D. Dunbabin, Mosaics of the Greek and Roman World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999. Pp. xxii + 357, 40 pls, 318 figs, 8 maps. ISBN 0-521-46143-X. £75.00". Journal of Roman Studies. 91: 200–201. doi:10.2307/3184782. JSTOR   3184782. S2CID   129788295. ProQuest   2212074666.
  44. 1 2 Harris, W. V. (2006). "A Revisionist View of Roman Money". The Journal of Roman Studies. 96: 1–24. doi:10.3815/000000006784016215. JSTOR   20430486. S2CID   163134314. ProQuest   2212083681.
  45. Howgego, Christopher (November 1992). "The Supply and Use of Money in the Roman World 200 B.C. to A.D. 300". Journal of Roman Studies. 82: 1–31. doi:10.2307/301282. JSTOR   301282. S2CID   162512195. ProQuest   2212059771.
  46. 1 2 3 Ligt, L. De (1 January 1991). "J. Andreau, La Vie Financière dans le Monde Romain. Les Métiers de Manieurs d'Argent (IVe Siècle av. J.C.-IIIe Siècle ap. J.C.) (Bibliothèque des Ecoles Françaises d'Athènes et de Rome, 265). Rome, Ecole Française de Rome, 1987. VIII, 792 p., 20 pl. Pr. FF. 570". Mnemosyne. 44 (3–4): 490–497. doi:10.1163/156852591X00378.
  47. 1 2 Grossman, Richard S. (26 May 2020). Unsettled Account: The Evolution of Banking in the Industrialized World Since 1800. Princeton University Press. pp. 32, 35. ISBN   978-0-691-20278-5. Archived from the original on 21 August 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  48. 1 2 3 Jean Andreau (1999). Banking and business in the Roman world. Internet Archive. Cambridge University Press. ISBN   978-0-521-38932-7.
  49. Geva, Benjamin (1 November 2011). The Payment Order of Antiquity and the Middle Ages: A Legal History. Bloomsbury Publishing. pp. 135–145. ISBN   978-1-84731-843-5. Archived from the original on 21 August 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  50. Focardi, Sergio M. (19 March 2018). Money: What It Is, How It's Created, Who Gets It, and Why It Matters. Routledge. ISBN   978-1-315-39104-5. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  51. Niczyporuk, Piotr (2014). "Bankierzy publiczni w starożytnym Rzymie". Zeszyty Naukowe Uniwersytetu Rzeszowskiego - Seria Prawnicza (in Polish) (14): 145–161. Archived from the original on 14 July 2020. Retrieved 22 August 2022.
  52. García Morcillo, Marta (2018). Banking in the Roman World. doi:10.1093/OBO/9780195389661-0312.
  53. Klauck, Hans-Josef; Leppin, Volker; McGinn, Bernard; Seow, Choon-Leong; Spieckermann, Hermann; Walfish, Barry Dov; Ziolkowski, Eric J, eds. (2011). Encyclopedia of the Bible and its Reception. Vol. 3. De Gruyter. doi:10.1515/ebr. ISBN   978-3-11-018371-9. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 23 August 2022.[ page needed ]
  54. Millet, Paul (2012). "Banks". In Hornblower, Simon; Spawforth, Antony; Eidinow, Esther (eds.). The Oxford Classical Dictionary. Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/acref/9780199545568.001.0001. ISBN   978-0-19-954556-8.
  55. Rathbone, D. W. (November 2001). "J. Andreau, Banking and Business in the Roman World (Key Themes in Ancient History).. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999. Pp. xix + 176, ISBN 0-521-38031-6(bound); 0-521-38932-1(paper). £37.50 (bound); £13.95 (paper)". Journal of Roman Studies. 91: 201. doi:10.2307/3184783. JSTOR   3184783. S2CID   164103856.
  56. Millett, Paul C. (20 December 2012), Hornblower, Simon; Spawforth, Antony; Eidinow, Esther (eds.), "banks", The Oxford Classical Dictionary, Oxford University Press, doi:10.1093/acref/9780199545568.001.0001, ISBN   978-0-19-954556-8, archived from the original on 3 August 2022, retrieved 3 August 2022
  57. Morcillo, Marta (24 May 2018). "Banking in the Roman World". obo. Archived from the original on 1 August 2022. Retrieved 1 August 2022.
  58. De Vries, T.; Zwalve, W. J. (2004). "Roman actuarial science and Ulpian's life expectancy table". Roman Rule and Civic Life: Local and Regional Perspectives. Brill. pp. 275–297. doi:10.1163/9789004401655_016. ISBN   978-90-04-40165-5. JSTOR   10.1163/j.ctv2gjwxqd.20.
  59. Andreau, Jean (2020). "Banks". The Encyclopedia of Ancient History. pp. 1–3. doi:10.1002/9781444338386.wbeah06036.pub2. ISBN   978-1-4051-7935-5. S2CID   241493769.
  60. 1 2 Moshenskyi, Sergii (2008). History of the Weksel: Bill of Exchange and Promissory Note. New York: Xlibris. pp. 40–42. ISBN   978-1-4363-0694-2. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  61. 1 2 3 Harris, W. V. (2008). "The Nature of Roman Money". The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans. pp. 174–207. doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199233359.003.0010. ISBN   978-0-19-923335-9.
  62. Millett, Paul C. (22 December 2015). "credit". Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Classics. doi:10.1093/acrefore/9780199381135.013.1919. ISBN   978-0-19-938113-5. Archived from the original on 3 August 2022. Retrieved 22 August 2022.
  63. Erdkamp, Paul; Verboven, Koenraad; Zuiderhoek, Arjan (18 February 2020). Capital, Investment, and Innovation in the Roman World. Oxford University Press. pp. 382–384. ISBN   978-0-19-257896-9. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  64. Schwei, David (2020). "An Explanation for the Addition of the Aureus to the Roman Imperial Coinage System". Classical Journal. 116 (2): 199–214. doi:10.1353/tcj.2020.0030. Project MUSE   801278 ProQuest   2466060172.
  65. Marzano, Annalisa (2022). "Chapter 5 the Personal Infrastructure of Maritime Trade". Roman Law and Maritime Commerce. pp. 57–76. doi:10.1515/9781474478168-009. ISBN   9781474478168.
  66. Hollander, David B. (2012). "Credit". The Encyclopedia of Ancient History. doi:10.1002/9781444338386.wbeah06091. ISBN   9781444338386.
  67. Kay, Philip (2014). Rome's Economic Revolution. doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199681549.001.0001. ISBN   978-0-19-968154-9.
  68. Homer, Sidney; Sylla, Richard (23 March 2011). A History of Interest Rates. John Wiley & Sons. p. 59. ISBN   978-1-118-04622-7. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  69. Bannock, Graham; Baxter, R. E., eds. (2011). The Penguin Dictionary of Economics, Eighth Edition. Penguin Books. p. 71. ISBN   978-0-141-04523-8.
  70. Kehoe, Dennis (2018). "Production in Rome". A Companion to the City of Rome. pp. 443–458. doi:10.1002/9781118300664.ch21. ISBN   978-1-118-30066-4. S2CID   165360045.
  71. Niczyporuk, Piotr (2013). "Operacje wykonywane przez bankierów rzymskich (argentarii)" [Transactions Performed by Roman Bankers (argentarii)]. Krytyka Prawa (in Polish). 5 (1): 481–506. Archived from the original on 3 August 2022. Retrieved 3 August 2022.
  72. Louis, Paul (5 November 2013). Ancient Rome at Work: An Economic History of Rome From the Origins to the Empire. Routledge. pp. 84–88. ISBN   978-1-136-60351-8. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  73. Toner, J. P. (25 April 2013). Popular Culture in Ancient Rome. John Wiley & Sons. ISBN   978-0-7456-5490-4. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  74. Wilson, Andrew; Bowmann, Alan (9 November 2017). Trade, Commerce, and the State in the Roman World. Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/oso/9780198790662.001.0001. ISBN   978-0-19-250797-6.[ page needed ]
  75. Adams, Samuel L.; Bradbury, Carlee; Bühler, Axel; Cheong, John; Chryssides, George D.; Chung-Kim, Esther; Gvaryahu, Amit; Hudnut-Beumler, James; Llewellyn Ihssen, Brenda; Mell, Julie; Sanders, Theresa; Stenschke, Christoph; Swindell, Anthony; Thompson, Trevor W.; Timani, Hussam. "Moneylending". Encyclopedia of the Bible and its Reception. doi:10.1515/ebr.moneylending. S2CID   245054874.
  76. Dari-Mattiacci, Giuseppe; Kehoe, Dennis P. (26 May 2020). Roman Law and Economics: Volume II: Exchange, Ownership, and Disputes. Oxford University Press. pp. 97–101. ISBN   978-0-19-109099-8. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  77. Holleran, Claire (26 April 2012). Shopping in Ancient Rome: The Retail Trade in the Late Republic and the Principate. Oxford University Press. p. 46. ISBN   978-0-19-162641-8. Archived from the original on 12 September 2022. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  78. Harris, W. V. (14 February 2008). Harris, W. V (ed.). The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans. OUP Oxford. doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199233359.001.0001. ISBN   978-0-19-923335-9.[ page needed ]
  79. Rovira-Guardiola, Charo (2012). "Loan, Greek and Roman". The Encyclopedia of Ancient History. doi:10.1002/9781444338386.wbeah13175. ISBN   978-1-4443-3838-6.
  80. Collins, Andrew; Walsh, John (2014). "Fractional Reserve Banking in the Roman Republic and Empire". Ancient Society. 44: 179–212. JSTOR   44079991.