Constructivism (ethnic politics)

Last updated

Constructivism presumes that ethnic identities are shapeable and affected by politics. Through this framework, constructivist theories reassesses conventional political science dogmas. Research indicates that institutionalized cleavages and a multiparty system discourage ethnic outbidding and identification with tribal, localized groups. In addition, constructivism questions the widespread belief that ethnicity inherently inhibits national, macro-scale identification. To prove this point, constructivist findings suggest that modernization, language consolidation, and border-drawing, weakened the tendency to identify with micro-scale identity categories. One manifestation of ethnic politics gone awry, ethnic violence, is itself not seen as necessarily ethnic, since it attains its ethnic meaning as a conflict progresses.

Contents

Defining ethnic identity

In contrast to primordialism, constructivism observes that ethnic identities are not unchanging entities. [1] Instead, political developments can shape which identities get activated. [2]

Chandra on ethnic identity

Under one conceptualization of ethnic identity, descent-based attributes—e.g., skin color—are the defining marker of ethnic identities. [3] Given the diversity of each individual's inherited attributes, everyone retains a "repertoire" of nominal identities that they can activate. [4] To illustrate this concept, Kanchan Chandra offers the fictitious example of Helen, a Trinidadian American. Among Helen's nominal identities are the following categories: African American, West Indian, Black. [5] In different contexts, Helen may emphasize different attributes, and by extension different identities, with which she identifies. To activate her membership in the West Indian or Black categories, she may decide to underscore attributes like her birth in Trinidad or her skin color, respectively. [6]

Two factors—Chandra maintains—qualify the extent to which someone can change their repertoire of nominal identities: constrained change and visibility. [7] The former factor acknowledges how many descent-based attributes, including skin color, are "sticky," i.e., restrictive of nominal identities and not easily changeable. [8] Chandra states that Helen, for example, cannot plausibly claim to be German if none of her parents have German descent; nor can Helen activate any other identity extraneous to her repertoire. [9] Moreover, "visibility" refers to the observability of descent-based attributes, since skin color, hair color, and the like are all noticeable and often carry an association with a particular ethnic identity. [10] Both constrained change and visibility regulate the category repertoire. [11]

With that being said, Chandra's framework does not foreclose the avenues of category change entirely. Explained by Chandra, it allows for five pathways:

  1. "Change in the Repertoire of Basic Descent-Based Attributes" - This pathway alters which attributes are salient to category determination. [12] In the U.S., as Chandra notes, skin color comprises a vital attribute that sways whom the public deems White, Black, etc. [13] In a different country—presumably one with less stark differences in skin color—ear length may matter more. [14] For post-colonial nations, a large determinant of which attributes receive emphasis, has been the census. [15] During Spanish colonial rule in Bolivia, census administrators classified landless peasants as mestizos , even though they did so because hacienda owners wanted to shield their landless peasant workers from taxation. [16] Nevertheless, land-owning status became a salient attribute vis-à-vis the mestizo category. [17]
  2. "Change in the 'Full' Repertoire of Nominal Ethnic Identity Categories" - Using the attributes they possess, individuals can construct new categories, though such change can only be long-term. [18] To consolidate any changes, institutional frameworks, including the census, codify them. [19] And newly constructed categories must remain logically consistent with their constitutive attributes. [20]
  3. "Change in the 'Operative' Repertoire of Nominal Identity Categories" - One's "operative repertoire" depends on the surrounding environment. [21] If those around Helen, a Trinidadian American, have never heard of Trinidad, then Helen's activation options are effectively constrained to her African American and West Indian identities. [22] Contextualization can therefore impact the nominal repertoire.
  4. "Individuals 'Passing' or 'Switching' Within an Existing Population Repertoire of Attributes" - At times, a person who possesses attributes that closely resemble those of another group's, can "pass" as a member of that group. [23] An outside observer may know little about the nuanced distinctions between Lapps and Norwegians. Yet since both ethnic identity groups have light skin and other similar features, a Lapp can pass successfully as a Norwegian, and vice versa. [24]
  5. "Reclassification of Activated Ethnic Identity Categories Within an Existing Repertoire of Categories" - Someone of biracial heritage, for instance, may emphasize one identity at work and another at home, directing attention toward the appropriate attributes—be they surname or birthplace. [25] For her part, Helen may activate her Trinidadian roots when situated with relatives or other Trinidadians, but activate her African American identity when situated with American-born friends or colleagues. [26]

Fearon and Laitin on ethnic identity

Like Chandra, James Fearon and David Laitin acknowledge the necessity of descent as a basis for ethnic identity membership rules. [27] They nonetheless differ in one noteworthy respect: Fearon and Laitin's approach places a premium on "cultural attributes," a concept which entails traditions, historical memories and legacies, religious and spiritual beliefs, etc. [28] In regard to changing ethnic identities, there are—theoretically speaking—three ways to bring about identity construction, namely socioeconomic trends, [29] discourse, [30] and individual action either by elites or by laypeople. [31]

Chandra on ethnic parties

Beyond an identity-level analysis, Chandra broadens her definitional theory to a central governing institution, the political party. There exists a difference between a multi-ethnic party and an ethnic one. The former denotes a party that excludes no ethnic groups, while the latter designates a party that performs some kind of exclusion. [32] Chandra lists seven benchmarks for gauging whether a political party is ethnic or not: (1) "Classification based on name"; [33] (2) "Classification based on explicit appeals," i.e., rhetoric that explicitly targets a specific ethnic group or groups; [34] (3) "Classification based on explicit issue positions"; [35] (4) "Classifications based on the implicit activation of ethnic identities," i.e., code words/phrases like dog whistles; [36] (5) "Classification based on a group's votes," i.e., whenever a certain ethnic group mostly and/or overwhelmingly backs a particular political party, excluding other groups from that party's support base; [37] (6) "Party votes," i.e., whenever a political party receives most of its vote share from a certain ethnic group or groups; [38] (7) "Ethnic leadership," i.e., the composition of the party leadership; [39] and (8) "Ethnic arena of contestation," i.e., whenever a political party competes only in certain ethnic enclaves or regions. [40] Exclusion, then, constitutes the key marker of an ethnic party, for it must exclude some ethnic group or groups via the aforementioned mechanisms. Otherwise, ethnic and multi-ethnic parties would remain definitionally indistinguishable. [41]

Voting behavior

One article written by Jóhanna Kristín Birnir posits that because new democracies operate in low-information environments—per the creation of novel, undefined parties—ethnic cleavages become an especially important source of information for voters. [42] Therefore, the more ethnically diverse a country is, the more stable its electoral results should be given the availability and visibility of ethnicity as a heuristic. [43] Birnir surveys the activation of different ethnic identity cleavages in 59 countries, [44] and examines Bulgaria as a case study, [45] concluding that linguistic identity is the most crucial cleavage during the infancy of a new democracy. [46] Birnir's study assesses the heterogeneity of democracies along linguistic and religious fractionalization, [47] and measures "electoral volatility" via the difference in parties' vote share across electoral cycles. [48] She finds that linguistic cleavages best anticipate said volatility. In many countries, Birnir asserts, linguistic barriers take precedence over racial ones, e.g., the Basques. [49] The Bulgaria analysis, too, concludes that Turkish-speaking voters had stable voting behavior in the 1997 and 2001 elections. [50] As for religion, it appears to be a cleavage that affects advanced, or "mature," party systems. [51]

Political institutions

Institutionalized cleavages

Chandra disputes the notion that the ethnicization of politics can lead to outbidding—i.e., ethnic polarization—which destabilizes democracy. [52] Her critique examines how India's constitutional structure enshrines (1) affirmative action for select castes, (2) the categorization of languages, and (3) the drawing of Indian states [53] —with a specific focus on the state of Uttar Pradesh. [54] In Chandra's telling, the Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP) moved to activate Hindu nationalism during the late 1980s and early 1990s. [55] Consequently, the Janata Dal Party used affirmative action to dangle patronage for "Other Backward Castes" and thereby targeted caste divisions within the Hindu community; this helped halt BJP outbidding. [56] The design of the Indian Constitution, then, allowed political actors to activate different ethnic identities at different times. [57] To remain viable, political parties must be able to attract diverse groups and compensate for losses incurred by the activation of a caste, religious, or some other identity; hence the moderation. [58] Importantly, the Indian Constitution leaves the definition of its affirmative action, linguistic, and statehood provisions open to revision. [59] Mitigating outbidding necessitates the institutionalization of cleavages with revisable definitions, so as to enable parties to leverage them for coalition-building. [60]

Party structure

According to Daniel Posner, one-party elections highlight local, tribal identities, whereas multiparty contests bring larger identities—be they regional, religious, or linguistic—to the fore. [61] When multiple parties vie for power, local political actors can associate themselves with a national party and thus "nationalize" a local election. [62] A one-party regime, by contrast, removes the competitiveness of a national contest, and leaves local elections as the only outlet for de facto electoral competition. [63] With the distractions of national political dynamics gone, local identities then assume greater salience. [64] In Kenya and Zambia, the adoption of a multiparty system boded a shift in the types of identities that political actors accentuated. [65] Posner argues that the adoption of a multiparty system underscored "language" cleavages in Zambia and "ethnoregional" ones in Kenya. [66] He arrives at this conclusion by identifying every individual who was a parliamentary candidate before and after the adoption, [67] and coded for those who belonged to the largest linguistic (Zambia) and ethnoregional (Kenya) groups within their respective electoral districts. [68] A multiparty system did accurately forecast the success of candidates tied to the aforementioned groups. [69]

Historical phenomena

Language consolidation

Posner provides a narrative as to how colonialism influenced the historical development and geography of Zambian languages. [70] He notes that colonial missionary, education, and labor practices winnowed the number of Zambian languages to four main ones: Bemba, Lozi, Nyanja, and Tonga. [71] The first practice—missionary work—encouraged linguistic consolidation in order to ease the translation of the Bible. [72] As for the second practice, colonial education officials made Bemba, Lozi, Nyanja, and Tonga the "languages of instruction," in 1927. [73] Meanwhile, the British South Africa Company (BSA), a mining corporation, orchestrated the migration of laborers toward company mines. [74] BSA actions directly contributed to the prevalence of Bemba speakers in the area known as the "copperbelt." [75] Furthermore, the company explicitly targeted them because their ancestral lands—in the northeast of Northern Rhodesia—were far removed from competing mines in Southern Rhodesia and South Africa. [76] The Bemba, BSA officials reasoned, would be less susceptible to alternative job offers, which threatened BSA profits by tendering better pay. [77]

Border-drawing

As Posner observes, border-drawing asymmetrically distributed the population shares of Chewas and Tumbukas, and generated the incentive structure of interethnic competition. [78] Chewa-Tumbuka relations are starkly different in Malawi and Zambia. [79] The relationship is hostile in the former, but cordial in the latter. [80] To be clear, Chewas and Tumbukas in Malawi and Zambia share similarities by and large, [81] especially because colonial authorities established the Malawi-Zambia border inattentively in terms of ethnic distribution. [82] After confirming the stark attitudes through a field experiment, wherein he surveyed villagers who live near the border, [83] Posner compares each group's share of the total population for both countries. With respect to Malawi, Chewas (28% share) and Tumbukas (12% share) were sizeable enough to comprise a political bloc in their own right. [84] The Zambian results, however, showed something else: Chewas (7% share) and Tumbukas (4% share) were much smaller as individual groups. [85] Zambia's unique demographic situation incentivized Chewas and Tumbukas to form a coalition together—given how each was too small to be viable politically—and construct an alliance as "Easterners." [86]

Modernization

Through public opinion data compiled and collected by Afrobarometer, [87] Amanda Lea Robinson investigates the relationship between modernization, ethnic diversity, and national identification, and she argues that modernization and ethnic diversity can induce the third outcome. [88] To measure the first two factors, she uses 2005 GDP per capita and the Ethno-Linguistic Fractionalization (ELF) index, respectively. [89] Modernization accurately predicts for increased national identification. In other words, the higher the GDP per capita for a given country, the higher the identification with a national identity. [90] More specifically, urban residency fosters a 3% boost in national identification. [91] Also, Robinson contends that diversity promotes political cohesion, not disunion. [92] As suggested before by Posner, without the overwhelming majority of any single ethnic group, a heterogeneous body politic can have an incentive to de-emphasize identities that are inadequate as singular entities and instead ally with other groups, e.g., the Zambian Chewas and Tumbukas. [93]

Ethnic violence

As previously mentioned, Fearon and Laitin identify three possible channels by which ethnic conflicts arise via identity construction: (1) "Social and Economic Processes as Agents of Construction," i.e., macrohistorical forces like modernization; [94] (2) "Social Construction by Discourse"; [95] and (3) "Individuals as Agents of Construction," whether they be elites or non-elites. [96] Fearon and Laitin's findings review several books—including Gérard Prunier's The Rwanda Crisis: History of a Genocide and Susan Woodward's Balkan Tragedy: Chaos and Dissolution After the Cold War [97] —and glean the conclusion that the first and second channels inadequately or unclearly explain ethnic violence. [98] "Individuals as Agents of Construction," though, presents a more promising explanation. [99] The Rwandan Genocide, after all, originated from elite manipulation of identity construction, given that colonial and Rwandan leaders assigned the Hutu-Tutsi terminology ethnic significance. [100] Prior to colonization, the terms indicated class rather than ethnicity. [101] Fearon and Laitin see evidence for non-elite culpability as well, observing that some opportunistic non-elites hear elite cues and use them as excuses to plunder, execute personal vendettas, and/or indulge in violence. [102]

Further developing the constructivist understanding of ethnic violence, Janet Lewis points out the "ethnicization" of conflict. Put simply, conflicts take on an ethnic significance over time, as opposed to being innately ethnic from their start. [103] Her case study—post-1986 Uganda—illustrates how ethnicity was originally negligible in the creation of insurgencies against the central government, and a great many soon ceased to operate. [104] Rather, the groups capable of "ethnic mobilization," were the ones that survived and eventually acquired the capacity to inflict violent acts. [105] Lewis assesses such an affiliation by determining which insurgent organizations sprung up in ethnically homogenous areas. [106] Equipped with the 1991 Ugandan census and the ELF index, [107] she found that ethnic homogeneity tracked an insurgent group's durability, though ethnicity did not engender these insurgencies per se. [108] Successful insurgent groups enjoyed, on average, an ELF score of .20, while those that ended up being unsuccessful produced an ELF score of .47. [109] As a result, the intersection of ethnicity and conflict did not really come about until after the conflict had commenced. [110]

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Ethnic conflict</span> Conflict between ethnic groups

An ethnic conflict is a conflict between two or more contending ethnic groups. While the source of the conflict may be political, social, economic or religious, the individuals in conflict must expressly fight for their ethnic group's position within society. This criterion differentiates ethnic conflict from other forms of struggle.

Political polarization is the divergence of political attitudes away from the center, towards ideological extremes.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Elections in Ghana</span> Political elections for public offices in Ghana

Elections in Ghana give information on election and election results in Ghana.

Consociationalism is a form of democratic power sharing. Political scientists define a consociational state as one which has major internal divisions along ethnic, religious, or linguistic lines, but which remains stable due to consultation among the elites of these groups. Consociational states are often contrasted with states with majoritarian electoral systems.

The Alliance for Democracy is a political party in Malawi that marked its history as laying the foundation for multi-party rule in Malawi. It began as an underground political movement during the Kamuzu Banda era and later evolved to a political party during the multi-party era under the leadership of trade union activist, Chakufwa Chihana. AFORD has a stronghold in the northern region. The president is Godfrey Shawa.

An ethnic party is a political party that overtly presents itself as the champion of one ethnic group or sets of ethnic groups. Ethnic parties make such representation central to their voter mobilization strategy. An alternate designation is 'Political parties of minorities', but they should not be mistaken with regionalist or separatist parties, whose purpose is territorial autonomy.

Primordialism is the idea that nations or ethnic identities are fixed, natural and ancient. Primordialists argue that each individual has a single inborn ethnic identity independent of historical processes. While implicit primordialist assumptions are common in society and much academic research, primordialism is widely rejected by scholars of nationalism and ethnicity, as individuals can have multiple ethnic identities which are changeable and socially constructed.

In international relations, constructivism is a social theory that asserts that significant aspects of international relations are shaped by ideational factors, not simply material factors. The most important ideational factors are those that are collectively held; these collectively held beliefs construct the interests and identities of actors.

James D. Fearon is the Theodore and Francis Geballe Professor of Political Science at Stanford University; he is known for his work on the theory of civil wars, international bargaining, war's inefficiency puzzle, audience costs, and ethnic constructivism. According to a 2011 survey of International Relations scholars, Fearon is among the most influential International Relations scholars of the last twenty years. His 1995 article "Rationalist Explanations for War" is the most assigned journal article in International Relations graduate training at U.S. universities.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Partition (politics)</span> Political border splitting a territory

In politics, a partition is a change of political borders cutting through at least one territory considered a homeland by some community.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Coup d'état</span> Deposition of a government

A coup d'état, also known as a coup or overthrow, is a seizure and removal of a government and its powers. Typically, it is an illegal seizure of power by a political faction, politician, cult, rebel group, military, or a dictator. Many scholars consider a coup successful when the usurpers seize and hold power for at least seven days.

Clientelism or client politics is the exchange of goods and services for political support, often involving an implicit or explicit quid-pro-quo. It is closely related to patronage politics and vote buying. Clientelism involves an asymmetric relationship between groups of political actors described as patrons, brokers, and clients. In client politics, an organized minority or interest group benefits at the expense of the public. Client politics may have a strong interaction with the dynamics of identity politics. This is particularly common in a pluralist system, such as in the United States, where minorities can have considerable power shaping public policy. The opposite of client politics is 'entrepreneurial' politics, or conviction politics.

In international relations theory, the bargaining model of war is a method of representing the potential gains and losses and ultimate outcome of war between two actors as a bargaining interaction. A central puzzle that motivates research in this vein is the "inefficiency puzzle of war": why do wars occur when it would be better for all parties involved to reach an agreement that goes short of war? In the bargaining model, war between rational actors is possible due to uncertainty and commitment problems. As a result, provision of reliable information and steps to alleviate commitment problems make war less likely. It is an influential strand of rational choice scholarship in the field of international relations.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Kanchan Chandra</span>

Kanchan Chandra is a political scientist who is currently Professor of Politics at New York University. She has made significant research contributions on a range of subjects in political science including comparative ethnic politics, constructivism, democratic theory, intrastate conflict, patronage and clientelism, and South Asian politics.

Negative partisanship is the tendency of some voters to form their political opinions primarily in opposition to political parties they dislike. Whereas traditional partisanship involves supporting the policy positions of one's own party, its negative counterpart in turn means opposing those positions of a disliked party. It has been claimed to be the cause of severe polarization in American politics. It has also been studied in the Canadian context, as well as in Australia and New Zealand. Cross-national studies indicate that negative partisanship undermines public satisfaction with democracy, which threatens democratic stability. Traditional partisans, on the other hand, are more likely to support their country's democracy, which promotes democratic stability.

David D. Laitin is the James T. Watkins IV and Elise V. Watkins Professor of Political Science in the School of Humanities and Science at Stanford University. He is a comparative politics scholar who has written works on civil war, ethnic identity, culture and nationalism. He is known for his application of rational choice to the study of ethnic conflict, and for bridging a gap between ethnography and rational choice.

Andreas Wimmer is a Swiss sociologist who is the Lieber Professor of Sociology and Political Philosophy at Columbia University. He has a PhD in social anthropology from the University of Zurich.

State capacity is the ability of a government to accomplish policy goals, either generally or in reference to specific aims. A state that lacks capacity is defined as a fragile state or, in a more extreme case, a failed state. Higher state capacity has been strongly linked to long-term economic development, as state capacity can establish law and order, private property rights, and external defense, as well as support development by establishing a competitive market, transportation infrastructure, and mass education.

Rational choice is a prominent framework in international relations scholarship. Rational choice is not a substantive theory of international politics, but rather a methodological approach that focuses on certain types of social explanation for phenomena. In that sense, it is similar to constructivism, and differs from liberalism and realism, which are substantive theories of world politics. Rationalist analyses have been used to substantiate realist theories, as well as liberal theories of international relations.

In international relations, credibility is the perceived likelihood that a leader or a state follows through on threats and promises that have been made. Credibility is a key component of coercion, as well as the functioning of military alliances. Credibility is related to concepts such as reputation and resolve. Reputation for resolve may be a key component of credibility, but credibility is also highly context-dependent.

References

  1. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. p. 2. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  2. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. p. 3. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  3. Chandra, Kanchan (2006-05-15). "What is ethnic identity and does it matter?". Annual Review of Political Science. 9 (1): 400. doi: 10.1146/annurev.polisci.9.062404.170715 . ISSN   1094-2939.
  4. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. p. 9. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  5. Chandra, Kanchan (2006-05-15). "What is ethnic identity and does it matter?". Annual Review of Political Science. 9 (1): 401. doi: 10.1146/annurev.polisci.9.062404.170715 . ISSN   1094-2939.
  6. Chandra, Kanchan (2006-05-15). "What is ethnic identity and does it matter?". Annual Review of Political Science. 9 (1): 416. doi: 10.1146/annurev.polisci.9.062404.170715 . ISSN   1094-2939.
  7. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. pp. 14, 16–17. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  8. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. p. 14. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  9. Chandra, Kanchan (2006-06-15). "What is ethnic identity and does it matter?". Annual Review of Political Science. 9 (1): 416. doi: 10.1146/annurev.polisci.9.062404.170715 . ISSN   1094-2939.
  10. Chandra, Kanchan (2006-06-15). "What is ethnic identity and does it matter?". Annual Review of Political Science. 9 (1): 416. doi: 10.1146/annurev.polisci.9.062404.170715 . ISSN   1094-2939.
  11. Chandra, Kanchan (2006-06-15). "What is ethnic identity and does it matter?". Annual Review of Political Science. 9 (1): 414, 416. doi: 10.1146/annurev.polisci.9.062404.170715 . ISSN   1094-2939.
  12. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. p. 153. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  13. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. p. 153. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  14. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. p. 153. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  15. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. p. 154. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  16. Jackson, Robert H.; Maddox, Gregory (1993). "The Creation of Identity: Colonial Society in Bolivia and Tanzania". Comparative Studies in Society and History. 35 (2): 268. doi:10.1017/S0010417500018375. ISSN   0010-4175. JSTOR   179400. S2CID   144307234.
  17. Jackson, Robert H.; Maddox, Gregory (1993). "The Creation of Identity: Colonial Society in Bolivia and Tanzania". Comparative Studies in Society and History. 35 (2): 268. doi:10.1017/S0010417500018375. ISSN   0010-4175. JSTOR   179400. S2CID   144307234.
  18. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. pp. 157, 159. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  19. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. p. 159. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  20. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. p. 157. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  21. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. p. 159. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  22. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. pp. 159–160. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  23. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. pp. 160–161. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  24. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. pp. 161–162. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  25. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. p. 162. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  26. Constructivist theories of ethnic politics. Kanchan Chandra. New York. 2012. p. 162. ISBN   978-0-19-989316-4. OCLC   865508263.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  27. Fearon, James D.; Laitin, David D. (2000). Brass, Paul; Deng, Francis M.; Kapferer, Bruce; McGarry, John; O'Leary, Brendan; Prunier, Gérard; Woodward, Susan L. (eds.). "Violence and the Social Construction of Ethnic Identity". International Organization. 54 (4): 848. doi:10.1162/002081800551398. ISSN   0020-8183. JSTOR   2601384. S2CID   11379085.
  28. Fearon, James D.; Laitin, David D. (2000). Brass, Paul; Deng, Francis M.; Kapferer, Bruce; McGarry, John; O'Leary, Brendan; Prunier, Gérard; Woodward, Susan L. (eds.). "Violence and the Social Construction of Ethnic Identity". International Organization. 54 (4): 848. doi:10.1162/002081800551398. ISSN   0020-8183. JSTOR   2601384. S2CID   11379085.
  29. Fearon, James D.; Laitin, David D. (2000). Brass, Paul; Deng, Francis M.; Kapferer, Bruce; McGarry, John; O'Leary, Brendan; Prunier, Gérard; Woodward, Susan L. (eds.). "Violence and the Social Construction of Ethnic Identity". International Organization. 54 (4): 851. doi:10.1162/002081800551398. ISSN   0020-8183. JSTOR   2601384. S2CID   11379085.
  30. Fearon, James D.; Laitin, David D. (2000). Brass, Paul; Deng, Francis M.; Kapferer, Bruce; McGarry, John; O'Leary, Brendan; Prunier, Gérard; Woodward, Susan L. (eds.). "Violence and the Social Construction of Ethnic Identity". International Organization. 54 (4): 851. doi:10.1162/002081800551398. ISSN   0020-8183. JSTOR   2601384. S2CID   11379085.
  31. Fearon, James D.; Laitin, David D. (2000). Brass, Paul; Deng, Francis M.; Kapferer, Bruce; McGarry, John; O'Leary, Brendan; Prunier, Gérard; Woodward, Susan L. (eds.). "Violence and the Social Construction of Ethnic Identity". International Organization. 54 (4): 853, 855. doi:10.1162/002081800551398. ISSN   0020-8183. JSTOR   2601384. S2CID   11379085.
  32. Chandra, Kanchan (2011-03-01). "What is an ethnic party?". Party Politics. 17 (2): 155. doi:10.1177/1354068810391153. ISSN   1354-0688. S2CID   143847044.
  33. Chandra, Kanchan (2011-03-01). "What is an ethnic party?". Party Politics. 17 (2): 159. doi:10.1177/1354068810391153. ISSN   1354-0688. S2CID   143847044.
  34. Chandra, Kanchan (2011-03-01). "What is an ethnic party?". Party Politics. 17 (2): 160. doi:10.1177/1354068810391153. ISSN   1354-0688. S2CID   143847044.
  35. Chandra, Kanchan (2011-03-01). "What is an ethnic party?". Party Politics. 17 (2): 161. doi:10.1177/1354068810391153. ISSN   1354-0688. S2CID   143847044.
  36. Chandra, Kanchan (2011-03-01). "What is an ethnic party?". Party Politics. 17 (2): 161–162. doi:10.1177/1354068810391153. ISSN   1354-0688. S2CID   143847044.
  37. Chandra, Kanchan (2011-03-01). "What is an ethnic party?". Party Politics. 17 (2): 162–163. doi:10.1177/1354068810391153. ISSN   1354-0688. S2CID   143847044.
  38. Chandra, Kanchan (2011-03-01). "What is an ethnic party?". Party Politics. 17 (2): 164. doi:10.1177/1354068810391153. ISSN   1354-0688. S2CID   143847044.
  39. Chandra, Kanchan (2011-03-01). "What is an ethnic party?". Party Politics. 17 (2): 165. doi:10.1177/1354068810391153. ISSN   1354-0688. S2CID   143847044.
  40. Chandra, Kanchan (2011-03-01). "What is an ethnic party?". Party Politics. 17 (2): 165. doi:10.1177/1354068810391153. ISSN   1354-0688. S2CID   143847044.
  41. Chandra, Kanchan (2011-03-01). "What is an ethnic party?". Party Politics. 17 (2): 157. doi:10.1177/1354068810391153. ISSN   1354-0688. S2CID   143847044.
  42. Birnir, Jóhanna Kristín (2007). "Divergence in Diversity? The Dissimilar Effects of Cleavages on Electoral Politics in New Democracies". American Journal of Political Science. 51 (3): 604. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00270.x. ISSN   1540-5907.
  43. Birnir, Jóhanna Kristín (2007). "Divergence in Diversity? The Dissimilar Effects of Cleavages on Electoral Politics in New Democracies". American Journal of Political Science. 51 (3): 602–619. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00270.x. ISSN   1540-5907.
  44. Birnir, Jóhanna Kristín (2007). "Divergence in Diversity? The Dissimilar Effects of Cleavages on Electoral Politics in New Democracies". American Journal of Political Science. 51 (3): 609. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00270.x. ISSN   1540-5907.
  45. Birnir, Jóhanna Kristín (2007). "Divergence in Diversity? The Dissimilar Effects of Cleavages on Electoral Politics in New Democracies". American Journal of Political Science. 51 (3): 614. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00270.x. ISSN   1540-5907.
  46. Birnir, Jóhanna Kristín (2007). "Divergence in Diversity? The Dissimilar Effects of Cleavages on Electoral Politics in New Democracies". American Journal of Political Science. 51 (3): 617. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00270.x. ISSN   1540-5907.
  47. Birnir, Jóhanna Kristín (2007). "Divergence in Diversity? The Dissimilar Effects of Cleavages on Electoral Politics in New Democracies". American Journal of Political Science. 51 (3): 611. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00270.x. ISSN   1540-5907.
  48. Birnir, Jóhanna Kristín (2007). "Divergence in Diversity? The Dissimilar Effects of Cleavages on Electoral Politics in New Democracies". American Journal of Political Science. 51 (3): 609. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00270.x. ISSN   1540-5907.
  49. Birnir, Jóhanna Kristín (2007). "Divergence in Diversity? The Dissimilar Effects of Cleavages on Electoral Politics in New Democracies". American Journal of Political Science. 51 (3): 613. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00270.x. ISSN   1540-5907.
  50. Birnir, Jóhanna Kristín (2007). "Divergence in Diversity? The Dissimilar Effects of Cleavages on Electoral Politics in New Democracies". American Journal of Political Science. 51 (3): 616. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00270.x. ISSN   1540-5907.
  51. Birnir, Jóhanna Kristín (2007). "Divergence in Diversity? The Dissimilar Effects of Cleavages on Electoral Politics in New Democracies". American Journal of Political Science. 51 (3): 613. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00270.x. ISSN   1540-5907.
  52. Chandra, Kanchan (2005). "Ethnic Parties and Democratic Stability". Perspectives on Politics. 3 (2): 235–252. doi:10.1017/S1537592705050188. ISSN   1537-5927. JSTOR   3688028. S2CID   33566400.
  53. Chandra, Kanchan (2005). "Ethnic Parties and Democratic Stability". Perspectives on Politics. 3 (2): 240. doi:10.1017/S1537592705050188. ISSN   1537-5927. JSTOR   3688028. S2CID   33566400.
  54. Chandra, Kanchan (2005). "Ethnic Parties and Democratic Stability". Perspectives on Politics. 3 (2): 243. doi:10.1017/S1537592705050188. ISSN   1537-5927. JSTOR   3688028. S2CID   33566400.
  55. Chandra, Kanchan (2005). "Ethnic Parties and Democratic Stability". Perspectives on Politics. 3 (2): 244. doi:10.1017/S1537592705050188. ISSN   1537-5927. JSTOR   3688028. S2CID   33566400.
  56. Chandra, Kanchan (2005). "Ethnic Parties and Democratic Stability". Perspectives on Politics. 3 (2): 244. doi:10.1017/S1537592705050188. ISSN   1537-5927. JSTOR   3688028. S2CID   33566400.
  57. Chandra, Kanchan (2005). "Ethnic Parties and Democratic Stability". Perspectives on Politics. 3 (2): 245. doi:10.1017/S1537592705050188. ISSN   1537-5927. JSTOR   3688028. S2CID   33566400.
  58. Chandra, Kanchan (2005). "Ethnic Parties and Democratic Stability". Perspectives on Politics. 3 (2): 245. doi:10.1017/S1537592705050188. ISSN   1537-5927. JSTOR   3688028. S2CID   33566400.
  59. Chandra, Kanchan (2005). "Ethnic Parties and Democratic Stability". Perspectives on Politics. 3 (2): 247. doi:10.1017/S1537592705050188. ISSN   1537-5927. JSTOR   3688028. S2CID   33566400.
  60. Chandra, Kanchan (2005). "Ethnic Parties and Democratic Stability". Perspectives on Politics. 3 (2): 248. doi:10.1017/S1537592705050188. ISSN   1537-5927. JSTOR   3688028. S2CID   33566400.
  61. Posner, Daniel N. (2007-11-01). "Regime Change and Ethnic Cleavages in Africa". Comparative Political Studies. 40 (11): 1302–1327. doi:10.1177/0010414006291832. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   154785072.
  62. Posner, Daniel N. (2007-11-01). "Regime Change and Ethnic Cleavages in Africa". Comparative Political Studies. 40 (11): 1307–1308. doi:10.1177/0010414006291832. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   154785072.
  63. Posner, Daniel N. (2007-11-01). "Regime Change and Ethnic Cleavages in Africa". Comparative Political Studies. 40 (11): 1308. doi:10.1177/0010414006291832. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   154785072.
  64. Posner, Daniel N. (2007-11-01). "Regime Change and Ethnic Cleavages in Africa". Comparative Political Studies. 40 (11): 1308. doi:10.1177/0010414006291832. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   154785072.
  65. Posner, Daniel N. (2007-11-01). "Regime Change and Ethnic Cleavages in Africa". Comparative Political Studies. 40 (11): 1321. doi:10.1177/0010414006291832. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   154785072.
  66. Posner, Daniel N. (2007-11-01). "Regime Change and Ethnic Cleavages in Africa". Comparative Political Studies. 40 (11): 1321. doi:10.1177/0010414006291832. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   154785072.
  67. Posner, Daniel N. (2007-11-01). "Regime Change and Ethnic Cleavages in Africa". Comparative Political Studies. 40 (11): 1312–1313, 1319. doi:10.1177/0010414006291832. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   154785072.
  68. Posner, Daniel N. (2007-11-01). "Regime Change and Ethnic Cleavages in Africa". Comparative Political Studies. 40 (11): 1313, 1319. doi:10.1177/0010414006291832. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   154785072.
  69. Posner, Daniel N. (2007-11-01). "Regime Change and Ethnic Cleavages in Africa". Comparative Political Studies. 40 (11): 1314, 1321. doi:10.1177/0010414006291832. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   154785072.
  70. Posner, Daniel N. (2003). "The Colonial Origins of Ethnic Cleavages: The Case of Linguistic Divisions in Zambia". Comparative Politics. 35 (2): 128. doi:10.2307/4150148. ISSN   0010-4159. JSTOR   4150148.
  71. Posner, Daniel N. (2003). "The Colonial Origins of Ethnic Cleavages: The Case of Linguistic Divisions in Zambia". Comparative Politics. 35 (2): 130. doi:10.2307/4150148. ISSN   0010-4159. JSTOR   4150148.
  72. Posner, Daniel N. (2003). "The Colonial Origins of Ethnic Cleavages: The Case of Linguistic Divisions in Zambia". Comparative Politics. 35 (2): 130. doi:10.2307/4150148. ISSN   0010-4159. JSTOR   4150148.
  73. Posner, Daniel N. (2003). "The Colonial Origins of Ethnic Cleavages: The Case of Linguistic Divisions in Zambia". Comparative Politics. 35 (2): 132. doi:10.2307/4150148. ISSN   0010-4159. JSTOR   4150148.
  74. Posner, Daniel N. (2003). "The Colonial Origins of Ethnic Cleavages: The Case of Linguistic Divisions in Zambia". Comparative Politics. 35 (2): 134. doi:10.2307/4150148. ISSN   0010-4159. JSTOR   4150148.
  75. Posner, Daniel N. (2003). "The Colonial Origins of Ethnic Cleavages: The Case of Linguistic Divisions in Zambia". Comparative Politics. 35 (2): 136. doi:10.2307/4150148. ISSN   0010-4159. JSTOR   4150148.
  76. Posner, Daniel N. (2003). "The Colonial Origins of Ethnic Cleavages: The Case of Linguistic Divisions in Zambia". Comparative Politics. 35 (2): 137. doi:10.2307/4150148. ISSN   0010-4159. JSTOR   4150148.
  77. Posner, Daniel N. (2003). "The Colonial Origins of Ethnic Cleavages: The Case of Linguistic Divisions in Zambia". Comparative Politics. 35 (2): 137. doi:10.2307/4150148. ISSN   0010-4159. JSTOR   4150148.
  78. Posner, Daniel N. (2004). "The Political Salience of Cultural Difference: Why Chewas and Tumbukas Are Allies in Zambia and Adversaries in Malawi". The American Political Science Review. 98 (4): 529–545. doi:10.1017/S0003055404041334. ISSN   0003-0554. JSTOR   4145323. S2CID   4496292.
  79. Posner, Daniel N. (2004). "The Political Salience of Cultural Difference: Why Chewas and Tumbukas Are Allies in Zambia and Adversaries in Malawi". The American Political Science Review. 98 (4): 530. doi:10.1017/S0003055404041334. ISSN   0003-0554. JSTOR   4145323. S2CID   4496292.
  80. Posner, Daniel N. (2004). "The Political Salience of Cultural Difference: Why Chewas and Tumbukas Are Allies in Zambia and Adversaries in Malawi". The American Political Science Review. 98 (4): 530–531. doi:10.1017/S0003055404041334. ISSN   0003-0554. JSTOR   4145323. S2CID   4496292.
  81. Posner, Daniel N. (2004). "The Political Salience of Cultural Difference: Why Chewas and Tumbukas Are Allies in Zambia and Adversaries in Malawi". The American Political Science Review. 98 (4): 531. doi:10.1017/S0003055404041334. ISSN   0003-0554. JSTOR   4145323. S2CID   4496292.
  82. Posner, Daniel N. (2004). "The Political Salience of Cultural Difference: Why Chewas and Tumbukas Are Allies in Zambia and Adversaries in Malawi". The American Political Science Review. 98 (4): 530. doi:10.1017/S0003055404041334. ISSN   0003-0554. JSTOR   4145323. S2CID   4496292.
  83. Posner, Daniel N. (2004). "The Political Salience of Cultural Difference: Why Chewas and Tumbukas Are Allies in Zambia and Adversaries in Malawi". The American Political Science Review. 98 (4): 531. doi:10.1017/S0003055404041334. ISSN   0003-0554. JSTOR   4145323. S2CID   4496292.
  84. Posner, Daniel N. (2004). "The Political Salience of Cultural Difference: Why Chewas and Tumbukas Are Allies in Zambia and Adversaries in Malawi". The American Political Science Review. 98 (4): 537–538. doi:10.1017/S0003055404041334. ISSN   0003-0554. JSTOR   4145323. S2CID   4496292.
  85. Posner, Daniel N. (2004). "The Political Salience of Cultural Difference: Why Chewas and Tumbukas Are Allies in Zambia and Adversaries in Malawi". The American Political Science Review. 98 (4): 537. doi:10.1017/S0003055404041334. ISSN   0003-0554. JSTOR   4145323. S2CID   4496292.
  86. Posner, Daniel N. (2004). "The Political Salience of Cultural Difference: Why Chewas and Tumbukas Are Allies in Zambia and Adversaries in Malawi". The American Political Science Review. 98 (4): 538–539. doi:10.1017/S0003055404041334. ISSN   0003-0554. JSTOR   4145323. S2CID   4496292.
  87. Robinson, Amanda Lea (2014). "NATIONAL VERSUS ETHNIC IDENTIFICATION IN AFRICA: Modernization, Colonial Legacy, and the Origins of Territorial Nationalism". World Politics. 66 (4): 718. doi:10.1017/S0043887114000239. ISSN   0043-8871. JSTOR   24577584. S2CID   144736858.
  88. Robinson, Amanda Lea (2014). "NATIONAL VERSUS ETHNIC IDENTIFICATION IN AFRICA: Modernization, Colonial Legacy, and the Origins of Territorial Nationalism". World Politics. 66 (4): 711. doi:10.1017/S0043887114000239. ISSN   0043-8871. JSTOR   24577584. S2CID   144736858.
  89. Robinson, Amanda Lea (2014). "NATIONAL VERSUS ETHNIC IDENTIFICATION IN AFRICA: Modernization, Colonial Legacy, and the Origins of Territorial Nationalism". World Politics. 66 (4): 722–723. doi:10.1017/S0043887114000239. ISSN   0043-8871. JSTOR   24577584. S2CID   144736858.
  90. Robinson, Amanda Lea (2014). "NATIONAL VERSUS ETHNIC IDENTIFICATION IN AFRICA: Modernization, Colonial Legacy, and the Origins of Territorial Nationalism". World Politics. 66 (4): 725, 727. doi:10.1017/S0043887114000239. ISSN   0043-8871. JSTOR   24577584. S2CID   144736858.
  91. Robinson, Amanda Lea (2014). "NATIONAL VERSUS ETHNIC IDENTIFICATION IN AFRICA: Modernization, Colonial Legacy, and the Origins of Territorial Nationalism". World Politics. 66 (4): 727. doi:10.1017/S0043887114000239. ISSN   0043-8871. JSTOR   24577584. S2CID   144736858.
  92. Robinson, Amanda Lea (2014). "NATIONAL VERSUS ETHNIC IDENTIFICATION IN AFRICA: Modernization, Colonial Legacy, and the Origins of Territorial Nationalism". World Politics. 66 (4): 727. doi:10.1017/S0043887114000239. ISSN   0043-8871. JSTOR   24577584. S2CID   144736858.
  93. Posner, Daniel N. (2004). "The Political Salience of Cultural Difference: Why Chewas and Tumbukas Are Allies in Zambia and Adversaries in Malawi". The American Political Science Review. 98 (4): 538–539. doi:10.1017/S0003055404041334. ISSN   0003-0554. JSTOR   4145323. S2CID   4496292.
  94. Fearon, James D.; Laitin, David D. (2000). Brass, Paul; Deng, Francis M.; Kapferer, Bruce; McGarry, John; O'Leary, Brendan; Prunier, Gérard; Woodward, Susan L. (eds.). "Violence and the Social Construction of Ethnic Identity". International Organization. 54 (4): 851. doi:10.1162/002081800551398. ISSN   0020-8183. JSTOR   2601384. S2CID   11379085.
  95. Fearon, James D.; Laitin, David D. (2000). Brass, Paul; Deng, Francis M.; Kapferer, Bruce; McGarry, John; O'Leary, Brendan; Prunier, Gérard; Woodward, Susan L. (eds.). "Violence and the Social Construction of Ethnic Identity". International Organization. 54 (4): 851. doi:10.1162/002081800551398. ISSN   0020-8183. JSTOR   2601384. S2CID   11379085.
  96. Fearon, James D.; Laitin, David D. (2000). Brass, Paul; Deng, Francis M.; Kapferer, Bruce; McGarry, John; O'Leary, Brendan; Prunier, Gérard; Woodward, Susan L. (eds.). "Violence and the Social Construction of Ethnic Identity". International Organization. 54 (4): 853, 855. doi:10.1162/002081800551398. ISSN   0020-8183. JSTOR   2601384. S2CID   11379085.
  97. Fearon, James D.; Laitin, David D. (2000). Brass, Paul; Deng, Francis M.; Kapferer, Bruce; McGarry, John; O'Leary, Brendan; Prunier, Gérard; Woodward, Susan L. (eds.). "Violence and the Social Construction of Ethnic Identity". International Organization. 54 (4): 845. doi:10.1162/002081800551398. ISSN   0020-8183. JSTOR   2601384. S2CID   11379085.
  98. Fearon, James D.; Laitin, David D. (2000). Brass, Paul; Deng, Francis M.; Kapferer, Bruce; McGarry, John; O'Leary, Brendan; Prunier, Gérard; Woodward, Susan L. (eds.). "Violence and the Social Construction of Ethnic Identity". International Organization. 54 (4): 851, 857. doi:10.1162/002081800551398. ISSN   0020-8183. JSTOR   2601384. S2CID   11379085.
  99. Fearon, James D.; Laitin, David D. (2000). Brass, Paul; Deng, Francis M.; Kapferer, Bruce; McGarry, John; O'Leary, Brendan; Prunier, Gérard; Woodward, Susan L. (eds.). "Violence and the Social Construction of Ethnic Identity". International Organization. 54 (4): 857. doi:10.1162/002081800551398. ISSN   0020-8183. JSTOR   2601384. S2CID   11379085.
  100. Fearon, James D.; Laitin, David D. (2000). Brass, Paul; Deng, Francis M.; Kapferer, Bruce; McGarry, John; O'Leary, Brendan; Prunier, Gérard; Woodward, Susan L. (eds.). "Violence and the Social Construction of Ethnic Identity". International Organization. 54 (4): 858, 865. doi:10.1162/002081800551398. ISSN   0020-8183. JSTOR   2601384. S2CID   11379085.
  101. Fearon, James D.; Laitin, David D. (2000). Brass, Paul; Deng, Francis M.; Kapferer, Bruce; McGarry, John; O'Leary, Brendan; Prunier, Gérard; Woodward, Susan L. (eds.). "Violence and the Social Construction of Ethnic Identity". International Organization. 54 (4): 858. doi:10.1162/002081800551398. ISSN   0020-8183. JSTOR   2601384. S2CID   11379085.
  102. Fearon, James D.; Laitin, David D. (2000). Brass, Paul; Deng, Francis M.; Kapferer, Bruce; McGarry, John; O'Leary, Brendan; Prunier, Gérard; Woodward, Susan L. (eds.). "Violence and the Social Construction of Ethnic Identity". International Organization. 54 (4): 871, 874. doi:10.1162/002081800551398. ISSN   0020-8183. JSTOR   2601384. S2CID   11379085.
  103. Lewis, Janet I. (2017-09-01). "How Does Ethnic Rebellion Start?". Comparative Political Studies. 50 (10): 1420–1450. doi:10.1177/0010414016672235. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   157893522.
  104. Lewis, Janet I. (2017-09-01). "How Does Ethnic Rebellion Start?". Comparative Political Studies. 50 (10): 1432, 1434. doi:10.1177/0010414016672235. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   157893522.
  105. Lewis, Janet I. (2017-09-01). "How Does Ethnic Rebellion Start?". Comparative Political Studies. 50 (10): 1434. doi:10.1177/0010414016672235. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   157893522.
  106. Lewis, Janet I. (2017-09-01). "How Does Ethnic Rebellion Start?". Comparative Political Studies. 50 (10): 1433. doi:10.1177/0010414016672235. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   157893522.
  107. Lewis, Janet I. (2017-09-01). "How Does Ethnic Rebellion Start?". Comparative Political Studies. 50 (10): 1433. doi:10.1177/0010414016672235. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   157893522.
  108. Lewis, Janet I. (2017-09-01). "How Does Ethnic Rebellion Start?". Comparative Political Studies. 50 (10): 1434. doi:10.1177/0010414016672235. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   157893522.
  109. Lewis, Janet I. (2017-09-01). "How Does Ethnic Rebellion Start?". Comparative Political Studies. 50 (10): 1434. doi:10.1177/0010414016672235. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   157893522.
  110. Lewis, Janet I. (2017-09-01). "How Does Ethnic Rebellion Start?". Comparative Political Studies. 50 (10): 1434. doi:10.1177/0010414016672235. ISSN   0010-4140. S2CID   157893522.